Wednesday, February 20, 2013

"Cosma Shalizi - Why Economics Needs Data Mining"

As part of a comment thread to this post on big data, Mark Thoma sends us here:



UPDATE:

I should have mentioned this before, but, while the entire segment is worthwhile, I was particularly glad to hear the interviewer address the strange discrepancy between the way economists use "data mining"  and the way statisticians, computer scientists and most people in business use term.



Tuesday, February 19, 2013

Interesting stats blog

From New Zealand. 

Education blogging of note

David Warsh has posted another entry in a thoughtful series about early childhood development. He also includes useful links including one to this interesting interview with James Heckman,

Monday, February 18, 2013

Yeah, I'm getting tired of these too

Once again I made the mistake of listening to On the Media. It started out reasonably benign with a standard but harmless piece on cyber-security, then went downhill with a smug piece on fact-checking before going off a cliff with this ddulite puff piece. Here's the blurb:
Late last month, The Washington Post debuted "The Truthteller," an application that it hopes will soon be able to fact-check politicians' speeches in real time using speech-to-text technology and a vast database of facts. Brooke talks to Cory Haik, The Washington Post's executive producer for digital news, about the app.
Of course, the speech-to-text and database problems are trivial next to the issues with processing natural language. To work at anywhere near the level discussed by Haik, the system would have to be considerably more advanced than IBM's Watson. Watson was designed to address short, free-standing questions following similar linguistic conventions and having clear, unambiguous answers.

This isn't meant to denigrate the team that developed Watson. Just the opposite. Interpreting natural language is extraordinarily difficult and solving even highly constrained problems is an impressive and important accomplishment. IBM has a lot to brag about.

The Washington Post currently has a beta up that apparently can sometimes spot strings that look like simple factual statements that lend themselves to automated comparison to a database. There's no reason to believe the app will ever move much beyond that, but the interviewer did believe...

without sign of suspicion...

immediately after a segment boasting about how carefully On the Media checks its facts.

To quote Snoopy, "the mind reels with sarcastic replies."

Sunday, February 17, 2013

When does original programming make business sense? part 1 -- cable

The big PR push (and credulous coverage) of Netflix's House of Cards has got me thinking about the necessary conditions for successfully launching an original scripted series. Before we get to the business case for Netflix, here are some thoughts on the current cable landscape.

When it comes to producing original content, the big players tend to fall into three groups (with one notable exceptions):

HBO
Showtime
USA
FX
TNT
Nick
Cartoon
AMC

Let's start slicing. Nick and Cartoon are certainly successful (SpongeBob is, by some standards, the most popular cable show ever) but animation and children's programming play by a very different set of rules. Production costs are extremely low and high audience turnover means that you can keep running the same few episodes for years. Furthermore, since children's programming works best in dedicated blocks, it's difficult for general interest channels to fully capitalize on this hugely profitable market. (Might throw Disney in here as well.)

Then there are the pay channels. Once again a very special business model. From a revenue standpoint, someone who watches five hours a month of Showtime counts the same as someone who watches fifty. What matters is loyalty. If you can bring in people with movies and specials, then get them sufficiently caught up in, say, Dexter, you don't have to worry about Starz stealing them away with better movies and specials. Better yet, if you can get fans of an older show like Dexter also hooked on a new show like Homeland, you can keep those monthly checks coming in for a long time.

This model does not work if your revenue comes from advertising. Having one show that a viewer never misses isn't nearly as valuable as having a bunch of shows that a viewer watches occasionally. This makes it extremely difficult for an expensive original cable show to pay for itself (particularly with a thirteen episode season). In this environment, viable shows have to add synergistic value. This brings us to the USA, FX and TNT, big flagship channels of ginormous media companies. These channels have the deep pockets, extensive synergies and long time frames that make it easier to make the business case for a Burn Notice or a Justified.

Which leaves AMC as the exception, the channel that would seem to suggest that anybody with good enough shows can make a go of original programming, but before an executive at AE points at AMC when greenlighting their next original drama, there are a couple of cautionary notes to keep in mind:

1. It's dangerous using outliers as examples

AMC got extraordinarily lucky twice, first in finding executives who could spot good shows and second in having good shows cross their desks. This is not something you can plan on in advance. In fact, it's something most companies fail at when they try.

2. (and this is the big one) It's not entirely clear that AMC is actually making money on this

It would take a good financial analyst and a lot of access to answer this definitively, but certainly looks like the network loses serious money on Mad Men and has been forced to make big and risky budget cuts to the show that is making them money, the ratings hit Walking Dead. Keep in mind, AMC has been both good and lucky. The odds against duplicating its success are slight and that success may not be all that, you know, successful.

These days, every cable channel seems to have an original scripted series in the works. From the executives' standpoint, this is easy to understand; these shows are the best way for a network to get prestige and media attention and who wouldn't want to be the VP who greenlit the next Breaking Bad? From the standpoint of the investor, though, if the channel isn't a TNT or an HBO or a Cartoon Channel, you might prefer another strategy.

Saturday, February 16, 2013

Weekend cinema buff alert

Hulu has temporarily lifted the paywall around the Criterion Collection. If you're a movie lover, you should definitely drop by.

p.s. but be prepared for LOTS of commercials.

The best tech writing you'll read this week just might be an article about wheelbarrows



I may may not always show it but I'm a great fan of technology (it's tough love, but love nonetheless). What I am not a fan of is the way that we discuss technology. Many (maybe most) journalists on this beat are so besotted with the gee-whiz aspects that they have little time to think seriously about why are certain technologies successful, what demands they makes on infrastructure, and how they answer existing needs and create new ones. (Search on 'ddulites' for more on this).

Having journalists report on the subject of their infatuation is generally a bad idea, but in this case the damage goes beyond the inevitable annoying prose. Technology is important and when we can't discuss it intelligently we make bad decisions that end up holding progress back.

Look at Groupon. One of the most exciting and promising areas of research today is the study of social networks, but partly because business reporters did such a poor job covering the subject, this crappy gift-card company was able to convince investors that its creaky business model was 'social.' (and no, requiring minimum orders for a deal to go through wouldn't have qualified even if they hadn't set the threshold meaninglessly low). The money that went to Groupon was diverted from other investments, including businesses that actually used the properties and analyses of social networks in their business plan.

Perhaps it's not surprising that the best thought-out, most clear-eyed popular writing on technology I've seen recently would focus on the least glamorous type of technology imaginable (via DeLong).







Wednesday, February 13, 2013

More fun with charts

Daniel Kuehn and Joseph previously discussed this post by Megan McArdle entitled "Department of Awful Statistics: Income Inequality Edition." They both make good points, but I'd like to approach this from the angle of appropriate visualization. McArdle supports her thesis that the middle class is neither disappearing nor getting poorer with charts derived from census table H-17 which you can and really should download here (the best way to keep us all honest is to play along at home).

The trouble is they're bad graphs.





To the extent that statistics includes data visualization, this is definitely bad statistics. When trying to depict trends and relationships, you generally want to get as much of the pertinent information as possible into the same graph. You don't want to force the reader to jump around the page trying to estimate slopes and compare magnitudes, nor do you want to take a few snapshots when you can easily picture all the data.

There are lots of acceptable ways of laying out the data table H-17, but I'm going just going to go with the simplest (partly because I like simple and partly because I'm doing this on Openoffice). As with McArdle's graphs, the numbers are inflation-adjusted.



I'm not that comfortable with this data (for reasons I'll get to in a minute), but this does look fairly consistent with the hollowing out of the middle class with 35K-75K (the top two lines) dropping more or less steadily for decades. Also check out the more than fourfold increase of people making more than 150K,

The two main things that make me uncomfortable with the data are the start point (with falls close to at least a couple of inflection points) and, on a related note, the failure to account for the baby boom which was at the bottom of its earning power forty years ago and should be close to the maximum now.

As far as I can tell income distribution is not broken down by age in these tables (though I suspect the data are available on request). We can, however, answer the related question of what median income looks like when we control for age and extended over a longer interval. (Download table P8 from here)




You can see why I was nervous about starting in 1967.

The question of income inequality and what's happening to the middle class is a complicated one and is probably best addressed by people who know what they're talking about, but if you are going to try to argue one side of the case graphically, you should at least take the time to use appropriate graphs.

p.s. I picked 35-44 because it seemed like a good representative mid-career interval and because, since I wasn't comparing different age groups, an uncluttered one-line graph seemed sufficient. If you prefer, here's the multi-range version (though I don't know if it adds much information).







Tuesday, February 12, 2013

Thinking about failure and collective amnesia.

No. Not in the sad my-life-adds-up-to-nothing way, but more in the case study sense. I've been noticing how often optimistic analyses of proposed products and business models echo the same arguments used over the years for various underperforming enterprises and catastrophic failures, invariably without a flicker of recognition.

No doubt, this is partly due to a general lack of long-term memory in the pundit class, but the problem seem particularly acute when it comes to failure. There are exceptions like this well-thought-out analogy by Josh Marshall or this piece of historical context for Zucker's Leno debacle from Kliph Nesteroff, but as a rule, most journalists don't pay nearly enough attention to these counterexamples (which makes it all the more difficult to avoid repeating mistakes).

I'll try to add some more entries and drill down into some of the specifics, but in the meantime, here's a short list of some potentially useful examples ideas that seemed (and in some cases, actually were) good ideas at the time.

The aforementioned mentioned attempt to make Jerry Lewis king of the talk shows.

A late Eighties format that doubled the resolution of video tapes while being completely compatible with standard VHS.

An attempt to break the Seventies DC/Marvel duopoly.

An attempt to break the Coke/Pepsi duopoly (perhaps breaking duopolies deserves a subcategory).

Adios, Amiga.

Friday, February 8, 2013

Fun with charts

This post by Daniel Kuehn is worth reading, although all of the action is in the comments. 

I think he is right on about the denomintor problem in interpreting her graphs.  It's also a very good example of when a point can be correct and yet not explain all of the differences (her comments about rounding).  However, the labeled buldge seems to be a lesser sin than variable bracket sizes on a density plot.

As for the change argument, it is fine to use a chart to explain something and then talk about the expected changes to the distribution.  Where I am less happy is that there are changes going on in the United States all of the time (aging of the population, propensity to form a new household) that are going to influence the shape of this curve.  It is possible to imagine the curve shifting exactly as Jon Evans suggested, and the reasons having to do with factors that have nothigng to do with inequality.

But standardized curves have their own issues . . .  So even Magan's use of the curve to show the shifts over time doesn't address the null conditional on the changes in the underlying population.  This may even help her argument, I am not sure, but certainly I would rather graph density plots in equal sized segments just for reader clarity

Still, a worthwhile argument to follow and it is useful insofar as it improves understanding of what the plots do and do not mean. 

Wednesday, February 6, 2013

Annals of bad analogies


From here:
Think about it this way. Say your elderly mother had to be hospitalized for life-threatening cancer. The best doctor in the region is at Sacred Heart, a Catholic, private hospital. Could you ever imagine saying this? “Well, I don’t think our taxpayer dollars should subsidize this private institution that has religious roots, so we’re going to take her to County General, where she’ll get inferior care. ’Cause that’s just the right thing to do!”
No. You’d want to make sure that your tax dollars got your mom the best care. Period. Our approach should be no different for our children. Their lives are at stake when we’re talking about the quality of education they are receiving. The quality of care standard should certainly be no lower.
An analogy is the weakest form of argument, because it presumes similarities between cases.  In this case we are equating a one time event (cancer treatment) with a long term process (educating people).  There is also a difference in that cancer outcomes are much easier to measure (due to the fast time between diagnosis and resolution) than an educational process.  So "better" is much easier to evaluate.  Finally, it ignores magnitudes.  What is "better" and by how much.  Is it a matter of preference (Starbucks coffee is better than McDonald's coffee) or an objective metric? 


But this whole thing dodges the main question-- why is the County General hospital not competitive with the Sacred Heart hospital?  Is that not the more interesting question?  Is it because the County General can't turn patients away and so gets the sickest of the sick? 

These points matter.   

Monday, February 4, 2013

Imbalance in the infrastructure debate

Joseph's previous post builds on this thread from Mark Thoma. Each is worth reading but I think both understate the extraordinary asymmetry between the pro and con in the should-we-spend-on-infrastructure debate (distinct from the where-to-spend debate). Consider the following statements:

1. We need to repair and upgrade the country's infrastructure in the relatively near future (let's say a decade)

So far as I can tell, almost no one is willing to stand up and argue against this point, which is strange because, though I don't happen to agree with them, there are reasonable arguments to be made here and, once this point has been conceded, the remaining ground is extraordinarily difficult to defend.

2. The economy is not operating at full capacity

We've already stipulated that we need to build these things which means we've also agreed to tolerate at least some crowding out at some point in the future. You simply can't have one without the other; you can only seek to minimize the effect. A crowding-out argument for delaying pretty much has to assume that there will be more slack in the economy far enough in the future to make waiting worth it (but not so far to extend past our decade window). I've heard lots of people making crowding-out arguments but none making the necessary corollary. (even if you believe that crowding out is unaffected by economic conditions, you still don't have any argument for waiting)

3. Borrowing costs for the federal government are historically low.

As a general rule, repairs don't get cheaper the longer you put them off. This tends to put the burden of proof on those arguing for a delay. If we were living in a period of historically high borrowing costs, you could argue that rates were likely to head back down if we waited. There are reasonable cost-based arguments against infrastructure spending, but only in the spend/don't spend context, not spend now/spend later.

The infrastructure debate is another example of how the public discourse has entered a phase reminiscent of Carroll's Tortoise/Achilles tale, where showing the premise is true and showing the premise leads to a conclusion is not sufficient to make the other side accept that conclusion. Of course, it's not an exact analogy. Carroll was making a point about the limits of logical system. What we're seeing here is more probably a demonstration of people's willingness to ignore the rules of argument when those rules lead to an uncomfortable policy position.

Friday, February 1, 2013

Sometimes you do it because it is a good idea anyway

Mark Thoma looks back five years to reports of skepticism about infrastructure development.  Part of this is that maybe we just need to relax our rules on project timelines a wee bit.  But another piece of it is that the worst mistake we can have to to end up competing with the private sector for labor to make cool things that we will end up needing.  As disasters go, this one is rather mild. 

Thursday, January 31, 2013

Shamisen heroes and free TV





I had been working on another piece about over the air television when I happened to surf across this video on one of the many Asian-themed channels you can get with an antenna in LA and it struck me as an appropriate accompaniment for a quick note about over the air TV.

With a pair of rabbit ears I pick up programming in at least a half dozen languages. That's an indication of the diversity of the medium and its importance to some underserved segments of the population, but it also represents a real competitive weakness. Terrestrial television suffers from a crippling lack of attention. Both Journalists who cover both media and personal finance are almost completely oblivious to this innovative, totally free source of programming.

If you're a medium trying to get the attention of the mainstream media, having a large part of your viewership consist of recent immigrants is not going  to help.

I'll leave you with something a bit more traditional from the Yoshida brothers, though still, well... Hell, just watch it.


Wednesday, January 30, 2013

Unintended consequences

I normally agree with pro-immigration stands, but this one strikes me as likely to do something different than expected:

While I think the region-based visa would be a positive step by itself, there is an additional twist I would recommend adding to the policy: require the purchase of a home from the visa recipient. This would be similar to the EB-5 program, which gives green cards to rich foreigners who invest in the U.S. This would allow non-rich immigrants to make an investment in the region sponsoring their visa. Not only does this increase the political popularity of the program and provide a way to transfer some of the gains of immigration to the native born population, but it also serves as an enforcement mechanism. Workers are less likely to leave the region their visa ties them too if they have made a large investment in that area which they cannot sell for the length of their visa.
 
I love the idea of a regional (i.e. state level) work VISA.  But the house thing is a terrible idea.  First of all, how do you get a loan?  If the requirement is "cash on the barrelhead" then we are only opening the market up to wealthy immigrants.  High skilled people just starting out are squeezed out of the market.  Or you get an asset, with little money down bought by people with a weak understanding of the local market who have the ability to flee overseas if things collapse. 

Nor am I sure we want even more price support for housing in the United States (mortgage deductions already support prices).  And I doubt that, in world with sublets, that this would really help keep people local over and above the what we already have in place. 

Plus, the rich enforcement mechanisms we have for work VISAs are already pretty scary, without adding this new level